|
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Working to lower remittance fees and provide innovative financing solutions for people, businesses, and governments |
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Future-Flow Securitization |
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Providing an existing asset as collateral
to secure a borrowing – such as a home mortgage or car loan – typically
reduces the borrowing cost. But in the absence of an existing collateral,
future-flows of earnings or revenue can be used as collateral. Such a
financing structure is termed Future-Flow Securitization.
It offers some of the most creative financing methods whereby billions of
dollars of bond financing have been raised by securitizing export revenues, tourism
receipts, credit card vouchers, remittances, payment rights, future
receivables from building new soccer stadiums, or even music and movies yet
to be produced. Sub-Saharan Africa can
potentially raise up to $17 billion annually via securitization of future
remittances and other future receivables, according to a 2008 paper Beyond Aid: New Sources and Innovative Mechanisms for Financing
Development in Sub-Saharan Africa. With proper planning, such transactions
can sustain external financing even during a crisis. What is FF securitization? See
below. A great resource for
future-flow securitization and a few other market-based (as opposed to
public-finance-based) innovative financing ideas is Innovative
Financing for Development published in October 2008. Or if you prefer a 4-pager, check out New Paths to Funding,
June 2009. A key requirement for issuing a bond is sovereign
rating, which may not exist in some countries, or if it does, it may be outdated.
This is the primary motivation behind the paper “Shadow Sovereign Ratings for Unrated Developing Countries,”
June 2007. (Listen to interview with Stephen
Evans, BBC Radio, aired on April 10, 2007) Leveraging Remittances for
International Capital Market Access, November 2005 (Photo
shows FF securitization structure) Recent Developments in Future-Flow
Securitization, December 2005 Securitization of Future Flow
Receivables: A Useful Tool for Developing Countries, March 2001 Financing Development through Future-Flow
Securitization, June 2002 Development Financing during a
Crisis: Future-Flow Securitization, April 2001 Future
Flow Securitization
(The following primer was created in October 2001 based on Ketkar and Ratha 2001) Securitization in emerging markets Structure
of future flow securitization How does
it improve credit rating? Benefits of future flow securitization Unused
potential in emerging markets What is
securitization?
Securitization is the process by which a borrowing
entity—a company or a bank in the public or private sector, or a sovereign or
sub-sovereign body—issues tradable securities backed by dedicated cash flows
from selected assets. The first securitized transactions occurred in the
United States in the 1970s and involved the pooling and repackaging of home
mortgages for resale as tradable securities by lenders. Since then, securitized markets have grown
in sophistication to cover a wide range of existing assets as well as future
assets. Among the best known cases of securitization
in the developing countries are the Brady bonds.
Existing assets that have been securitized in recent years include bank loans
and lease financing, and future flow receivables such as export receivables, credit
card receivables, telephone receivables, and non-recourse project
financing. (See also ABS, CBOs, CLOs, CMOs) See also Giddy (1994, pp 486-489) Securitization in emerging
markets
Rated vs. unrated transactions. Securitization
transactions can be classified according to whether these are rated or not
rated by major credit rating agencies, and within each of these categories,
according to whether they involve existing assets or future receivables. It is hard to obtain information on unrated
securities issued by developing country entities which are typically
underwritten by commercial banks that either keep them on their own books or
distribute them through private placement.
Nevertheless, it is believed that rated transactions may be more prevalent
in emerging market economies with relatively more developed capital markets. Existing asset vs. future asset securitization. Securitization of existing assets (such as
lease financing) as well as future assets (such as workers’ remittances) are
being used by developing country entities for raising finance. Existing asset
securitization is increasing in importance and can be a big aid to the
development of local capital markets.
But since existing assets are denominated in local currency, their role
in raising external finance may be limited. The first important future flow securitized transaction
in a developing country occurred in 1987 with the securitization of telephone
receivables due to Mexico’s Telmex. Since then the three principal rating agencies---Fitch
IBCA, Duff and Phelps (Fitch), Moodys and Standard
& Poors (S&P)---have
collectively rated several hundred securitization transactions with the
aggregate principal amount totaling approximately $100 billion. Structure of future
flow securitization
In a typical future flow
transaction, the borrowing entity in a developing country sells its future
product to an offshore Special Purpose Entity (SPE), which issues the debt
instrument (see box for an example). By a legal arrangement between the
borrowing entity and major international customers, payments for the future
product are directly deposited in an offshore collection account managed by a
trustee. The debt is serviced from
this account, and excess collections are forwarded to the borrowing entity in
the developing country. How does it improve
credit rating?
The transaction structure outlined above mitigates several elements of the default
risk. The ability of the government to interfere with debt servicing
is greatly reduced by the offshore payment arrangements. The market risk
arising from price and volume volatility is mitigated using
over-collateralization. The risk that
a product may be sold to other than designated customers depends on the
choice of collateral: such risks tend to be low for crude oil and for credit
card receivables (because crude such as Maya from Mexico is sold to a limited
number of buyers who have the refining capacity, and there are only a handful
of major credit card companies); in contrast, diversion risks are high for
agricultural staples. Various Types of Risks Involved in Future Flow Securitization Sovereign risk: will the originator’s government take steps to
disrupt the payment arrangement set out in the structured transaction? Performance risk: will the originator have the ability and
willingness to produce and deliver the product? Product risk: will there be sufficient demand for the product at
a stable price and will the buyer meet his payment obligations? Diversion risk: can the product or the receivable be diverted to
customers other than designated customers. Additionally, there are currency devaluation risk, bankruptcy
risk and political risk, which are related to sovereign risk. The usual transfer and convertibility risks
are substantially mitigated when hard currency future flow receivables are
securitized via an SPV structure. Keeping in mind the performance, product and sovereign risks,
the rating agencies have arrived at the following hierarchy of future flow
receivable transactions in terms of deals that are most secure to those that
are least secure. The securitization of heavy crude oil receivables is deemed
to be most secure while the securitization of future tax receipts is thought
to be least secure.
It is possible to securitize future flow receivable
transactions even at the lowest end of the hierarchy shown in Table 1. An example of this is the securitization
of co-participation tax revenues (via federal tax sharing) by several
Argentine provinces (Standard & Poor’s 1999). Of course, it becomes more difficult to
obtain investment grade transaction rating as one moves to the lower end of
the hierarchy. Alternatively, it
becomes necessary to build in more safeguards to improve credit rating as one
moves down the hierarchy. (The ability to structure away sovereign risks is
greatly reduced at the height of a liquidity crisis. The risk mitigation through future flows
structure works best when sovereign risk perception are
high and liquidity is low, but not during a full-blown crisis.) Insurance companies are playing a rising role in the 1990s
insuring the various elements of risk described above. A number of
insurance companies – MBIA, Ambac, FGIC among them – have provided financial
guarantee. Benefits of
future-flow securitization
In the 1990s, many borrowing entities in
developing countries that had a higher local currency rating than their
government were able to pierce the sovereign foreign currency credit ceiling
by using securitization of future receivables. The innovative structuring of
these transactions allowed borrowers to obtain significantly lower interest
rates and longer maturity than on their own unsecured bonds or government eurobonds. To the investors, the attractiveness of this
asset class lies in its good credit rating and its stellar performance in
good as well as bad times. Their investment grade rating allows future
flow-backed securities to attract a wider class of investors including, for
example, insurance companies that face limitations on buying sub-investment
grade papers. Also, the price of future flow securities tends to be less
volatile than that of unsecured debt which is another reason why investors
like this asset class. Moreover, there
have been no debt defaults on rated future flow asset-backed securities
issued by developing country entities, despite repeated crises of liquidity and/or
solvency. An interesting example is the telephone receivable deal of
Pakistan’s public sector telephone company—Pakistan
continued to service this debt even in the face of selective default on its
sovereign debt. However, while this
track-record of no-default is encouraging, the test has not been stringent
enough yet. This is in part because
the size of this asset class has been small relative to that of unsecured
debt. Does securitization increase the cost of unsecured
debt? According to the efficient market hypothesis, pledging a part of
receivables to back securitized notes should affect the ability of the
borrower to service the remainder of its debt. However, market participants
argue that this would be the case only when securitized debt rises
significantly above certain critical levels.
One reason behind this lack of effect of securitization on unsecuritized debt is that by achieving investment-grade
ratings, asset-backed securities attract a wider range of investors including
insurance companies and pension funds who are constrained to buy only
investment grade assets (Giddy 1994, p 487).
Another reason may be that the benefits of securitization may improve
the ability of the entity to service its unsecured obligations. For example, a bank may profit from lower
capital costs (for meeting capital adequacy requirements) if it offloads a
part of its loans through securitization.
Other explanations rest on the presence of market imperfections. For example, unsecured liabilities may be
guaranteed by the government (e.g., by deposit insurance in the case of a
bank). Unused potential in
emerging
markets
Future flow securitization has significant potential
for growth because such transactions allow issuers to pledge receivables over
a number of years. The potential for future flow
securitization from developing countries appears far more than the level of
current issuance. The potential
outside Latin America, especially in Eastern Europe and Central Asia, is also
quite large. Countries in the Middle
East have large oil receivables that can be securitized to raise
capital. In South Asia and Africa, the
potential for securitization lies in remittances, credit card vouchers, and
telephone receivables. Constraints on future-flow securitization. A major constraint on the growth of future
flow transactions arises from the paucity of good collateral in developing
countries. (Oil is an example of good
collateral for several reasons. The
stock of oil in a country is more or less
known. Well-developed global markets
make oil a highly “liquid” asset.
Given its importance to a nation’s economy, chances of government
interference in oil exports are low.
Finally, the risks that exports may be diverted to foreign importers
not covered in a securitization structure is low in the case of oil exports,
especially crude oil exports.) Other constraints to securitization include the absence
of high-quality issuers. Securitization deals tend to be complex and involve
high preparation costs and long lead-times.
The lack of legal clarity on bankruptcy procedures in many developing
countries adds further impedimenets to these
deals. In some cases, policy makers
are simply not familiar with this mechanism. Many issuers cannot—or do not
want to—assume the burden of full disclosure of information in a timely
fashion. Others worry about whether
pledging future receivables might taint their creditworthiness. Public policy issues
Future-flow securitization, however, increases inflexible
debt of the issuer as well as the nation.
Although the current level of future flow debt is nowhere near the
danger level in any country, such debt combined with debt from other preferred
creditors can reduce the flexibility in debt servicing and jeopardize
issuer creditworthiness. However,
inflexibility in debt servicing may be (arguably) a good thing in many
developing countries, especially in those with a history of misallocation of
public debt. (Rating agencies have not downgraded sovereign credit ratings of
either Mexico or Venezuela on account of their high
securitized debt. Mexico’s securitized
debt of around $19 billion is about 16 percent of its total debt, and
Venezuela’s securitized debt of nearly $6 billion is 18 percent of its total
debt.) Nevertheless, if developing country entities do need to
borrow to smooth consumption or investment over business cycles, they may
find this asset class attractive. If planned and executed ahead of time, it
can provide a way of accessing markets during times of liquidity crisis. Another attractive aspect of this structure
is that the value of the underlying collateral—for example, worker
remittances, credit card receivables, or oil exports—may rise during a
crisis, thus, making this asset counter-cyclical in nature. (For example,
Mexico’s real exports rose 30 percent and real imports declined 8 percent in
1995.) For many developing countries,
future flow receivable-backed securitization may be the only way to begin
accessing international capital markets. Considering the long lead times
involved in future flow deals, however, even public sector
entities would need to keep securitization deals in the pipeline and
investors engaged in good times so that the asset class remains accessible
during a crisis. An equally important incentive for governments to
promote this asset class lies in the externalities associated with future
flow deals. Future flow deals involve
a much closer scrutiny of the legal and institutional environment than
unsecured transactions. Besides, the
preparation of a future flow transaction often involves reforms of the legal
and institutional environment. These
reforms would facilitate domestic capital market development and encourage
international placements as in the aftermath of the Brady deals in the early
1990s. Public policy to facilitate future flow-backed
securitization should focus on relaxing the above constraints. Transaction costs can be reduced through
expansion of the scale of these deals by planning a series of issues by the
same issuer (the so-called master trust arrangement). The size of the deals
can also be raised via receivable pooling. (Telephone companies in several
Caribbean countries, for instance, could pool their receivables from
international telephone calls for securitization. It is not easy, but may be
possible, to avoid the complication arising from relatively more creditworthy
entities subsidizing less creditworthy entities using innovative structures. See
Standard and Poor’s 2001.)
Establishment and use of indigenous credit rating agencies to obtain
domestic credit rating can also reduce transaction costs, although care has to be taken in mapping local rating scales to
international scales. Certain segments of this asset class—such as
securitization of oil receivables—may be amenable to standardization
and a cookie-cutter approach.
Clarification of bankruptcy laws will be helpful for all
financial deals including securitization.
Also, educating policy makers and potential issuers about the
benefits and risks of this asset class will help. IBRD’s negative pledge. Future flow securitization can
potentially conflict with the negative pledge provision included in IBRD loan
and guarantee agreements. This
provision does not prohibit the creation of security in favor of other
creditors. Instead, it prohibits the
establishment of a priority for other debts over the debt due to the IBRD.
However, the IBRD may grant a waiver in respect of this clause in certain
circumstances, in particular, when transactions
involve small amounts (World Bank Operational Manual OP7.20). Examples: Two Transactions by Petroleos Mexicanos
Mexico’s state-owned oil and gas company, Petroleos Mexicanos (Pemex) is
to date the largest emerging market issuer of future flow-backed structured
notes. Two large transactions
undertaken by Pemex after the crisis of 1994/95 are discussed below. A. United Mexican States (Pemex) and the
U.S. Treasury rescue package of 1994-95 Amount $ 6 billion, closing date of transaction August
5, 199, maturity 5 years (2001), interest three-month LIBOR plus 2 percent,
payable quarterly, Depositaries: Swiss Bank Corporation, New York Branch and
the Federal Reserve Bank of In August 1996, the United Mexican States issued $6
billion in structured notes backed by exports of crude oil and oil
derivatives by Pemex. This transaction
used a modified version of the structure used in the ($20 billion) financing
of the rescue package by the U.S. Treasury in February 1995. The proceeds were used for repaying the
U.S. Treasury financing. In this
structure, Pemex’s export sales subsidiaries, PMI Comercio Internacional (PMI) and PMI Trading, irrevocably
instructed their customers to make all payments for exports into designated
accounts at the Swiss Bank Branch in New York (depositary), which was in turn
instructed to transfer 57.14 percent of all funds on deposit to a transaction
account owned by Banco de Mexico at the FRBNY, and the remainder to a trustee
account for servicing the structured notes.
In the event of a payment default to the U.S. Treasury or the holders
of the notes, FRBNY was authorized to debit the transaction account of Banco de
Mexico for amounts then due under the notes, for making payments to debt
holders. According to Standard and Poor’s, the credit rating of
the structured notes did not benefit from the involvement of the FRBNY which
acted only as a depositary, nor from that of the U.S. Treasury, since the
obligations due to the latter were scheduled to mature before the notes’
final maturity in 2001. B. Pemex Finance Limited Amount: Nine issuances during 1998 and 1999, each up to
$500 million. Future US dollar receivables owed to Pemex Finance Ltd. by
designated customers who will receive Mayan crude oil from Pemex Exploracion y Produccion (PEP),
via Petroleos Mexicos Internacional (PMI). Rating BBB. PMI arranges to sell Mayan crude oil, or some other
crude oil type if Mayan becomes unavailable, to designated customers who
agree to deposit their payments into an offshore collection account. PMI, a subsidiary of Pemex, is the
distributor for Mayan crude oil, which is produced by PEP. Pemex Finance Ltd. is the offshore issuer
of notes. It purchases the receivables
from PMI via the offshore Pemex subsidiary, PMI Services. The diagram shows that sales of the crude oil to
designated customers and of receivables to PMI Services are out of the
jurisdiction of the Mexican government.
The first claim on the receivables is from the note holders, and the
Mexican central bank is not involved in the process. Chase Manhattan Bank has
agreed to administer the issuance of all debt and the payment of interest and
principal on such debt in accordance with Pemex’s agreements. After paying note holders principal and
interest, excess payments, based on fluctuation in crude oil prices, are paid
to PMI Services and PMI, via the offshore collection account. While this structure mitigates the usual convertibility
and transfer risks, other risks still remain.
Primarily, there is a risk that a fluctuation in crude oil prices will result
in revenues insufficient to cover the interest and principal due to note
holders. The overcollateralization of
the notes minimizes this risk – PMI will provide a minimum coverage ratio of
three times the amount needed for payment of interest and principal.
Designated customers have also signed agreements acknowledging their
commitment to purchase crude oil and to make any future payments into the offshore
collection account. Further enhancing
the strength of such issuance is Pemex’s track record of timely servicing of
debt in the past. As
a result of these enhancements, S&P rated the credit of 1998 and
1999 tranches A-2 and A-4 and 1999 tranche A-5 as BBB. Rated as AAA are 1998 and 1999 tranches A-1
and A-3, as they are insured by MBIA and AMBAC. These ratings are clearly favorable
relative to the BB foreign currency rating of the United Mexican States. Example:
Pakistan Telecommunications Co Ltd (PTCL)
No default on asset-backed papers even in the face of
selective default on sovereign debt In 1997, the Pakistan Telecommunications Company
Limited (PTCL) issued $250 million in bonds backed by future telephone
settlement receivables from AT&T, MCI, Sprint, British Telecom, Mercury
Telecommunications and Deutsche Telekom. Even though the Government of
Pakistan owns 88 percent of PTCL, this issue was rated BBB- by S&P, four
notches higher than the B+ sovereign rating. Following the detonation of nuclear devices in May
1998, Pakistan’s economy and creditworthiness deteriorated rapidly. Investors became concerned that faced with
increasing official demands for equal burden sharing, the government might
place the future flow receivable-backed securities in a single basket with
all other sovereign debt and interfere with PTCL’s debt servicing. The Government of Pakistan rescheduled its
Paris Club debt obligations on January 30, 1999 and signed a preliminary
London Club agreement on July 6, 1999 to reschedule $877 million of sovereign
commercial loan arrears. But PTCL’s
future flow net receivable backed bonds were not subjected to any rescheduling
or restructuring, although their rating was downgraded several times during
1997-98 (see table below). Partly this
was because the amount required to service these obligations made up only 30
percent of the total net telephone receivables of the company. But the main reason was that there was a
strong incentive on the sovereign’s part to keep servicing the bonds and not
jeopardize the operation of the local telephone network and even more
importantly risk severing Pakistan’s telecommunication link to the rest of
the world.
Further reading
Fitch IBCA, Duff & Phelps. International
Structured Finance Criteria Reports. Various issues. Giddy, Ian H. 1994. Global Financial
Markets. Moody’s. 2001. Revised Country Ceiling Policy: Rating
Methodology. Standard & Poor’s. 2001. “New
Rating Criteria for Multiple-Credit-Dependent Obligations.” May. . |
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
|
|
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||